|
New
York State
Assembly
|
 |
|
|
|
|
February 19999
|
|
|
Dear Reader,
This paper examines the actions taken in the past two
years by the Governors New York State Public Service
Commission (NYPSC) to administratively restructure the electric
industry. Without seeking legislative authority and guidance
concerning the transition from monopoly regulation to market
competition, the NYPSC decided six separate cases that dealt
with rate levels, retail competition, and corporate restructuring
of six of New Yorks investor-owned electric utilities.
The unsatisfactory results for New Yorks electric
consumers, described here, provide compelling evidence that
a comprehensive legislative approach to electric utility
restructuring is required.
A description of energy legislation and additional papers
on energy are available from the Assembly Press Office,
by calling (518) 455-3888, or through the Assembly Internet
location (www.assembly.state.ny.us).
|
|
Shedding Light On
The Governors Failed
Electric Utility
Restructuring
A Briefing Paper on
Moving to Competition
in the Electric Industry
Sheldon Silver
Speaker of the Assembly
Michael J. Bragman
Majority Leader of the Assembly
Paul D. Tonko, Chair
Assembly Standing Committee on Energy
|
Shedding
Light On Electric Utility
Restructuring In New York State
|
The New York Public Service Commission (NYPSC) issued a series
of decisions beginning in September, 1997 approving settlement
agreements with six of New Yorks seven major electric utilities.
The settlements: established rates to be effective over the next
four to five years; permitted the utilities to change their corporate
structure; provided for either the separation or sale of non-nuclear
generating plants from the regulated utility; and set a schedule
for the implementation of "retail access," at which
time customers will be able to choose their electricity supplier.
The transmission and distribution (T&D) portion of the utility
would continue to be regulated, but electric generation would
be deregulated and subject to competition.
The settlements involved Central Hudson Gas & Electric Corp.
(CenHud), Consolidated Edison Company of New York, Inc. (Con Edison),
New York State Electric & Gas Corp. (NYSEG), Niagara Mohawk
Power Corp. (NiMo), Orange & Rockland Utilities, Inc. (O &
R), and Rochester Gas & Electric Corp. (R G & E).
|
The
NYPSC decisions offer few benefits and
impose substantial costs on utility ratepayers.
|
- Overall rate reductions fall far short of the
level needed to bring New Yorks electric
prices in line with national average electric
prices, leaving New Yorkers bur- dened with the
second-highest electric rates in the country,
keeping New Yorks businesses at a competitive
disadvantage, and costing the State thousands
of jobs.
- Because of rate cuts in other states,
New York customers may find the
price gap between New York and
other states growing.
- Many customers will likely see bill
increases.
- Most customers will realize only
minimal rate cuts.
|
- The most substantial rate reductions
are limited to the very largest
business customers.
- Some planned rate reductions will
be eliminated by numerous
settlement provisions allowing for
future rate increases.
- Stranded costs are largely imposed
on utility customers, with
shareholders assigned virtually
none of these costs.
- Rules established for competition
between utilities and alternative
electric suppliers will not result in
lively competition or produce
substantial benefits for customers.
|
|
|
Criteria
For Assessing The Restructuring Settlements
|
To evaluate the NYPSCs recent decisions regarding electric
industry restructuring, this paper identifies five specific criteria
that reasonably gauge the benefits provided to electric consumers.
These criteria involve the rate reductions provided to consumers,
the manner in which "stranded costs" are addressed,
and the availability to consumers of viable competitive electric
supply options.
Criterion #1: Overall rate reduction. How significant
is the level of rate reduction in percentage terms compared
to existing rates? How much progress does the rate reduction
represent in moving the utilitys overall rate level toward
the national average price for electricity?
Criterion #2: Rate equity. Are rate reductions
distributed fairly among residential, commercial, and industrial
customers? Will price structure changes, such as adjustments
in minimum monthly service charges and energy prices, be implemented
in a way that minimizes the potential for customer bill increases?
Criterion #3: Rate certainty. How secure can
consumers be that promised rate reductions will actually occur
over the next several years? Have automatic increases for less
predictable costs, such as fuel, been eliminated? Have procedures
permitting the utility to obtain rate increases been kept to
a minimum?
Criterion #4: Stranded cost treatment. Are the
interests of customers and utility stockholders balanced in
the treatment of stranded costs?
Criterion #5: Access to competitive suppliers.
Have obstacles to participation by potential competitive electric
suppliers been minimized? Will customers gain access to competitive
sources on a reasonable schedule? Have the rules for retail
access ensured that impediments to customer choice cannot be
erected by the monopoly utility?
|
Overall
Rate Reductions
|
The overall rate reductions called for by the NYPSCs decisions
are far smaller than required to make New Yorks electric
prices competitive. Promised rate reductions are insufficient
to make substantial progress in bringing New Yorks average
prices within reach of the national average, and, in most cases,
will have a nearly unnoticeable effect on customers bills.
Measuring Rate
Reductions
Because each of the NYPSCs decisions sets rates for
a number of years, and because each utility begins with rates
that exceed national average electric prices by varying degrees,
at least two different measures of overall rate changes are
meaningful.
The total customer bill savings measures the
difference between the utilitys total revenue at current
rates and at reduced rates, over the term of the settlement.
The total customer bill savings, expressed as a percent, provides
an indication of the total dollar savings to be provided to
consumers.
The maximum overall rate cut measures the percentage
change in rates achieved by the end of the settlement term.
The maximum overall rate cut indicates the final rate reduction
provided to consumers, whether it is provided immediately or
phased in over time.
A significant disparity between the total customer bill savings
and the maximum overall rate cut indicates that only a small
portion of the rate reductions are provided in the early stages
of the settlement term. If, on the other hand, the entire rate
reduction is provided at the beginning of the settlement term,
then the total customer bill savings and the maximum overall
rate cut would be equal. Neither of these measures accounts
for potential rate adjustments that may be allowed to cover
unanticipated cost changes, an issue that is addressed in the
context of the rate certainty criterion. Except in those cases
where adequate data did not exist, all rate changes were calculated
here to exclude the effect of the recently enacted reduction
in the Gross Receipts Tax (GRT), since it would occur in any
event.
Table
1
Rate Cuts Fail
to Close Price Gap
Table 1 presents the total customer bill savings and maximum
overall rate cut provided in each of the recently approved rate
settlements. Table 2 presents more detail on the rates produced
by the settlements and compares them to the 1996 national average
price for electricity of 6.86 cents per kilowatt-hour (kwh).
All percentage rate changes are in the single-digits. Customers
of Central Hudson, Orange & Rockland, and Niagara Mohawk
may not even notice the small rate reductions they receive.
As for the extent to which the rate settlements help move New
Yorks electric prices closer to the national average,
Table 2 shows very little progress. When the likelihood of rate
reductions in other states is considered, New York electric
customers may actually lose ground and find the price gap between
New York and the rest of the nation growing.
Table
2
|
Rate
Equity
|
The most substantial rate reductions are limited to the very largest
business customers under the terms of the settlements approved
by the NYPSC. The vast majority of customers, namely residential
and small business customers, will realize only small rate reductions
and, in some cases, no reductions at all. A significant number
of customers will actually see their electric bills increase because
of the recent NYPSC decisions.
Most Customers
Get Poor Deal
Table 3 presents a summary of the distribution of rate reductions
between those customers receiving the largest benefits ("Best
Deal") and those receiving the smallest benefits ("Worst
Deal"). The rate reductions shown are the maximum reductions
offered, which are often provided only in the final year of
the four- to five-year settlement period. In every case, the
greatest rate reductions are offered only to industrial customers
or to the largest commercial and industrial (C&I) customers.
Some Customers
Face Bill Increases
The inequitable distribution of rate reductions among different
categories of customers is made worse by rate structure changes
incorporated in several of the settlements approved by the NYPSC.
Rate structure changes included in the Niagara Mohawk settlement
would have increased bills for 44 percent of residential customers
and 55 percent of small commercial customers. Although the NYPSC
did not approve the immediate implementation of these changes,
it will consider them again in 1999, when Niagara Mohawk submits
its detailed proposal for the rates that will apply when retail
access is implemented for residential and commercial customers.
In the case of Rochester Gas & Electric, the NYPSC approved
an increase in the fixed monthly customer charge for residential
and small business customers. As a result, 27 percent of residential
customers and an unspecified percentage of small business customers
will experience bill increases even after the overall reduction
in rates is implemented.
Table
3
|
Rate
Certainty
|
While each of the rate settlements approved by the NYPSC establishes
rates for a four- to five-year period, the rates are not guaranteed.
To varying degrees, the rate settlements include rate mechanisms
automatic adjustments, surcharges, deferrals for later
recovery, and further rate increase requests to address
increased costs or revenue shortfalls that the utility may face
over the course of the settlement period. In addition to these
settlement provisions, each settlement allows for a rate mechanism
designed to recover stranded costs. The effect of the stranded
cost recovery mechanism on customer rates in the future is unknown
but potentially enormous. Additional uncertainty exists for the
period following the expiration of the rate settlements. At that
time, utilities may request whatever rate changes they believe
they can justify.
Rate Adjustments for
Cost Increases
Each utility is provided some means to recover costs that
are imposed in the future by changes in laws or regulations.
Table 4 presents examples of other costs that can be recovered
and the manner by which the utility will be permitted to recoup
its higher-than-anticipated costs. The customers of NYSEG are
unlikely to face significantly different prices than provided
for in the settlement, because of the very limited settlement
provisions for passing through cost increases to customers.
However, all other electric customers in New York will have
no assurance that the prices provided for in the settlements
approved by the NYPSC will be the prices that they will pay.
All or a portion of the rate reductions scheduled to be implemented
under the terms of the settlements could be offset by surcharges
and rate adjustments designed to cover cost increases. Niagara
Mohawk has openly stated its expectation that the small rate
reductions provided to the companys residential and commercial
customers in the first three years of the settlement could be
wiped out by rate increases allowed in years four and five.
Stranded Cost
Rate Adjustments
One key factor that could have a sizable impact on customers
bills in the future is the rate mechanism designed to recover
stranded costs. A stranded cost recovery mechanism, generally
referred to as a competitive transition charge (CTC), has been
approved by the NYPSC in each of the six electric rate settlements.
In most cases, the CTC will be imposed as a charge on customers
bills for an indefinite period of time. More importantly, the
amount of the CTC is not known; although there are provisions
in the settlements that address how the CTC will be calculated,
the amount of the charge will depend on developments in the
electric market that cannot be predicted.
Table
4
|
Stranded
Cost Treatment
|
In nearly every case, the NYPSC has assigned most of the responsibility
for stranded costs to electric ratepayers (see page 11 for description
of stranded costs). This result runs contrary to one of the
guiding principles the NYPSC itself established for the transition
to competition. In its 1996 decision adopting principles for
competition, the NYPSC explicitly rejected the notion that utility
shareholders should recover all stranded costs from ratepayers,
and instead decided that the assignment of responsibility for
stranded costs would require a balancing of ratepayers
and shareholders interests.
While "just and reasonable" rates must reflect
a reasonable balancing of ratepayer and shareholder interests,
they may or may not include stranded investment.
. . . New York State law does not require the public to pay
excessive rates in order to provide a company a return on
stranded investment.
. . . We have considerable leeway to set rates that balance
ratepayer and shareholder interests. While we do not accept
[the utilities] legal arguments, we are not rejecting
appropriate rate recovery. Cost recovery will ultimately depend
upon the particular circumstances of each utility.
Case Nos. 94-E-0952 et. al., Opinion
and Order Regarding Competitive Opportunities for Electric Service,
issued and effective May 20, 1996, pp. 49-51, footnotes omitted.
Most Stranded
Costs Charged to Customers
The settlements approved by the NYPSC dealing with Central
Hudson and NYSEG explicitly provide for full recovery of stranded
costs from ratepayers. A requirement that Con Edison stockholders
absorb $300 million in stranded costs can be avoided if Con
Edison can show that it has taken steps to develop a competitive
market. In the RG&E case, the stranded cost issue was deferred
until the end of the settlement period. O & Rs shareholders
were held responsible for a share of stranded costs, but the
sale of O & Rs generating plants resulted in a net
gain, leaving no stranded costs. Only NiMos share- holders
are expected to accept a significant share of stranded costs,
by forgoing between $1.4 billion and $2 billion in earnings
over the term of the settlement approved by the NYPSC. Even
then, NiMo will be allowed to recover its original investment
costs from customers.
The Effect of
Stranded Costs on Rates
It is not possible to calculate the effect on rates of the
NYPSCs decisions to impose most stranded cost responsibility
on customers. Although estimates of the magnitude of stranded
costs for individual utility companies were offered by a number
of parties involved in the cases, the estimates frequently varied
widely, and no consensus estimates are available. However, there
is sufficient information available to offer a few examples
of the effect of stranded costs on rates. In the RG&E case,
the NYS Consumer Protection Board (CPB) proposed that one-eighth
of the utilitys stranded costs be charged to stockholders,
in order to reduce rates by an additional 3.4 percent. In the
CenHud case, the CPB recommended that shareholders absorb just
over five percent of total stranded costs to provide an additional
rate cut of five percent. Neither of these proposals was adopted
by the NYPSC. However, these examples show that the effect of
stranded costs on rates varies from one utility to another,
and that the NYPSCs failure to require stockholders to
share in the burden of stranded costs translates to a significant
rate-cutting opportunity lost.
|
Access
To Competitive Suppliers
|
Deregulation of electric generation will only bring benefits to
consumers if a truly competitive market is brought into existence
(see page 12 for a description of competitive retail electric
markets). The rules established by the NYPSC to govern competition
are unlikely to foster a thriving competitive market, and, so,
are unlikely to provide benefits to consumers. One critical factor
that will determine whether or not competition succeeds is the
back-out rate, against which alternative suppliers must compete.
Setting the back-out rate requires judgement as to which costs
should be attributed to the T&D system, as opposed to electric
generation. Setting the back-out rate too low is likely to stifle
competition. The pace at which consumers are allowed access to
competitive electric suppliers will also have a significant effect
on the speed with which competition takes hold. Other, less measurable,
factors include the ease with which potential competitors can
enter the market, and the existence of clear rules that prevent
utility affiliates from gaining an unfair competitive edge. For
example, a utility affiliate that is allowed to use the utilitys
name and trademark has a competitive edge, due to name recognition,
that some utility analysts estimate can offset a 10 percent price
discount offered by competitors. Another factor that may or may
not affect the extent of competition, but is likely to affect
consumer satisfaction, is the degree to which all customers are
allowed to participate in competitive electricity shopping at
or around the same time. Consumer perceptions of competition may
be negatively affected if some customers are allowed to shop for
electricity before others.
Inadequate Back-out
Rates Will Stifle Competition
The NYPSC has approved different methods for calculating the
back-out rates, or shopping credits, that will determine how
much customers will pay for delivery of electricity from competitive
electric suppliers (see page 11 for a description of back-out
rates). Back-out rates represent the benchmark against which
competitors must price their product in order to offer customers
savings compared to the regulated utilitys supply. Although
different back-out rates have been approved for each of the
six utilities covered by the recent NYPSC decisions, some preliminary
conclusions can be drawn from the back-out rates approved for
the two largest utilities, Con Edison and NiMo. The outlook
for competition in New York State is not bright in large part
because of the back-out rates approved for these two companies.
Con Edison and NiMo will have back-out rates, or shopping credits,
based on the wholesale market price for electricity. Both utilities
will provide incentives to encourage customers to switch electric
suppliers, but the funding for those incentives is limited both
in amount and duration. Back-out rates that are set, like Con
Edisons and NiMos, no higher than wholesale prices
are unlikely to be high enough to allow truly competitive markets
to form. Since most competitors will be buying power at wholesale
prices, they must charge something higher than wholesale prices
to cover such costs as marketing, account management, and administrative
overhead. Yet, if competitors charge a price higher than the
wholesale price, and the back-out rate or shopping credit is
equal to the wholesale price, customers will rightly choose
to stay with the regulated utility company, since that will
be the cheapest option available.
The back-out rates for some of the other utilities do not suffer
the same infirmities as Con Edisons and NiMos, since
they include an additional credit amount, above the wholesale
price for power, to account, for example, for the cost of retailing.
However, Con Edison and NiMo, taken together, serve the vast
majority of electric customers in the service territories of
the six utilities covered by the NYPSCs recent decisions.
Inadequate back-out rates for those two companies are likely
to put a substantial damper on the extent to which electric
competitors become active in New York State and are certain
to reduce the cost saving potential of electric competition
for consumers.
Tax Advantages
For Competitors Will Disappear
While back-out rates are set too low to allow for effective
competition, some retail competition has been spurred by the
different tax treatment applied to sales by non-regulated electric
suppliers. Electric competitors have been exempt from certain
sales-based taxes, and customers choosing alternative suppliers
have been able to realize up to five percent savings as a result.
These savings have been enough to foster competition for those
customers singled out for early retail access.
However, a change in the interpretation of state tax laws will
result in the elimination of this tax advantage for electric
competitors. A January 1, 1999 ruling by the State Department
of Taxation and Finance reverses an earlier decision and eliminates
the exemption of the delivery of non-regulated electric sales
from state and local sales taxes. Proposals have been made to
delay the effectiveness of the new tax law interpretation. Nevertheless,
the elimination of the tax advantage for competitive electric
suppliers, when implemented, will foreclose the only real opportunity
for customers to obtain savings from electric competition under
the NYPSCs approach.
Retail Access
Rules Create Obstacles to Competition
A number of barriers to effective competition have been created
by the retail access schedules adopted by the NYPSC, not the
least of which is the lack of uniformity among utilities. Table
5 indicates the final deadline for all customers to be offered
retail access as well as the scheduled elapsed time between
the initial offering of retail access to some customers and
the date by which all customers are offered access to competitive
suppliers. Potential competitors will be unable to conduct state-wide
marketing campaigns because of the different schedules. The
drawn out phase-in periods for introducing retail access within
each service territory will complicate customer recruitment
and limit competitors advertising and marketing options.
In addition, the NYPSC has not precluded the use by unregulated
utility affiliates of the utility name or trademarks, so competing
energy suppliers will typically be at a competitive disadvantage
in marketing against utility-affiliated energy suppliers. These
obstacles to competition can be expected to translate into fewer
active competitors, less aggressive competition, and smaller
cost-saving opportunities for customers.
Table
5
|
The
Results And The Process
|
Each of the six NYPSC decisions came as a result of settlements
among some of the parties, the NYPSC staff, and the relevant
utility. However, most of the cases were settled on terms that
were unacceptable to nearly every party representing residential
and small business customers, and only one settlement was endorsed
by a majority of the parties involved. The NYPSC process that
produced the rate settlements was open to public participation
in a technical sense, but not a practical one. The process by
which each of the settlements was negotiated and reviewed was
complex, costly, and extraordinarily time-consuming. The six
different cases ran generally in parallel, and, on several occasions,
negotiations or hearings were held in different cases during
the same week. The ability of consumers and consumer groups
to participate in the process was put to the extreme test by
the burden imposed by the process itself. In addition, the NYPSC
settlement guidelines, requiring that all parties be notified
of and allowed to participate in negotiations, were waived in
the Con Edison, O & R, RG&E, and NYSEG cases. Although
this was done to allow the parties more flexibility, the effect
was to limit the serious negotiations to representatives of
the utilities, the NYPSC staff, and one or two prominent parties,
generally representing large industrial customer interests.
The result of this process was a series of settlements that
were subject to wide opposition among participating parties.
In the negotiations that led to the settlements approved by
the NYPSC, the NYPSC staff was working from a weak bargaining
position against the utilities. The fact that all affected electric
utilities had sued the NYPSC, challenging its legal authority
to order the introduction of retail competition, clearly weakened
the bargaining position of the NYPSCs staff in negotiations
with the utilities. Since dropping their lawsuit against the
NYPSC was a strong bargaining chip on the side of the utilities,
the utilities were able to make more favorable deals for themselves.
In addition, the NYPSC had indicated a strong preference for
negotiated settlements rather than the more usual process by
which the NYPSC issues a decision after hearings. As a result,
the NYPSC staff could not credibly threaten to walk away from
the bargaining table and pursue the normal hearing process.
A key negotiating tactic was effectively unavailable to the
NYPSC staff, further weakening their position and strengthening
the position of the utilities. Further, the NYPSC turned a blind
eye to the opportunity to require better deals for customers
that a clear statutory requirement for retail competition could
have afforded. Such a mandate would have neutralized the utility
lawsuits and provided the NYPSC with a firm foundation from
which to require better deals for consumers.
|
Problems
In Implementing Competition
|
The implementation of competition in New York, as designed by
the NYPSC, has thus far revealed a series of missteps by the
Administration and unexpected consequences for customers. In
implementing competition for natural gas customers, the NYPSC
first ruled that regulated gas distribution companies would
not be allowed to perform simple maintenance for customers,
including re-lighting pilot lights. Only after an outcry from
the public did the NYPSC reverse course and permit gas utilities
to perform these important services for customers. Another mid-course
correction involves the changing interpretation of tax laws,
discussed earlier, which has introduced an element of uncertainty
in an important aspect of the business environment for customers
and electric suppliers.
Although retail access is not yet available to most electric
customers, a number of unforeseen problems have already arisen
from the NYPSCs actions to introduce competition. NiMo
customers have discovered that they now must pay a fee for the
privilege of paying their electric bills to banks and pharmacies
that have traditionally accepted utility bill payments from
customers. Con Edison customers who choose alternative electric
suppliers and opt to make a single payment to their new supplier,
including charges for Con Edisons delivery services, have
discovered that they may have to pay twice for Con Edisons
service, if the new supplier fails to pass along the customers
payment to Con Edison. Thus far, as these problems have arisen,
it has been the consumer who has suffered. As retail access
continues to be implemented, further problems such as these
can be expected to arise.
|
The
Question Of Securitization
|
Proposals to "securitize" the stranded costs of New
York States electric utilities have been submitted for legislative
consideration each of the past three years. These proposals, like
securitization programs proposed, and in some cases adopted, in
other states offer the prospect of reducing the interest costs
paid by consumers to service utility debt. Recent developments
in the capital markets have dramatically reduced the cost of debt
generally, and the potential benefits of securitization are much
lower than they would be in a higher interest rate environment.
But whatever the level of potential interest savings, any benefits
of securitization should be weighed against the fact that securitization
would lock stranded cost recovery into consumer rates. Even if
future lawmakers or regulators were to determine that some or
all of the stranded costs that had been securitized should properly
be the responsibility of utility stockholders, they could do nothing
to remedy the situation.
Legislative authority for securitization that does not clearly
set out the criteria by which utilities will be allowed to issue
securitized bonds runs the obvious risk of forcing utility customers
to pay for costs that should not be their responsibility. Securitization
legislation, as proposed by the Administration, does not include
clear guidelines and criteria, but instead designates the NYPSC
as the body responsible for deciding which costs may be securitized
and subject to irrevocable rate orders. In considering whether
a broad mandate to issue irrevocable rate orders should be given
to the NYPSC, it is important to examine that bodys track
record in the six electric restructuring cases recently concluded.
The NYPSCs recent decisions, described in this briefing
paper, should give pause to those who would give that agency
unbridled authority to approve utility requests for securitization,
and instead support the notion that specific, unambiguous standards
are an essential component of any comprehensive electric restructuring
legislation which could include authority for securitization.
|
Concepts
And Definitions
|
Stranded Costs are the book costs of existing utility investments
that have traditionally been recovered in a regulated utilitys
rates but would not be recoverable in a competitive market. In
essence, in a competitive market, a utility cannot charge a price
high enough to recover stranded costs because rivals will be willing
to supply electricity at a lower price. An example of the costs
that would be stranded in a transition to competition are those
associated with nuclear power plants that cost far more to build
than conventional power plants. As the previously regulated electric
generation portion of the industry moves to a competitive market,
the NYPSC plans to allow stranded costs associated with electric
generation to be imposed on the customers of the remaining regulated
monopoly utility (the transmission and distribution portion of
the electric utility).
A Back-out Rate, sometimes called a "shopping
credit," is subtracted from the utilitys full-service
rate for customers buying electricity from alternative suppliers.
Theoretically, the back-out rate should be calculated to equal
the costs that are saved by the regulated T&D utility when
it avoids the need to generate electricity and maintain enough
generating capacity to meet expected demand for customers that
buy their electricity elsewhere. What is left after these avoided
costs are subtracted from the full-service rate should equal
what it costs to deliver electric supplies to customers.
The higher the back-out rate, or shopping credit, the more inducement
there is for customers to shop for power and the greater the
opportunity for competitive electric suppliers. If a competitor
charges more than the back-out rate for the electricity it sells,
the customer would be better off purchasing electricity directly
from the T&D utility, which will remain a "provider
of last resort" for customers that do not buy electricity
from a competitive electric supplier. Therefore, competitors
either must sell electricity at a price below the back-out rate,
or must provide a higher quality or more valuable service, in
order to attract customers.
How Retail Electric Competition Would Work: Competition
in the electric industry need not fit a specific mold, as there
are numerous choices, for policy-makers and electric suppliers
alike, in establishing the framework and structure for competition.
Nevertheless, certain general observations can be made about
the likely form that electric competition would take if policy-makers
choose to open the industry to retail competition.
The transmission and distribution of electricity would remain
regulated, with prices for these services set by regulators
based on traditional ratemaking methods. The supply of electricity
by generating companies, or unregulated generation affiliates
of regulated utilities, would be subject to competition. Purchasers
would buy electricity from competing electric generators, with
transmission and delivery provided by regulated T&D utilities.
Very large businesses might buy directly from electric generators,
but most smaller customers are likely to buy electricity through
energy marketers or energy service companies (ESCOs). ESCOs
would recruit customers to sign up for their "brand"
of electricity, much like long-distance telephone companies
do now. ESCOs could differentiate themselves from each other
through prices, customer service, "green" power sources,
or by offering additional services, such as energy efficiency
services, natural gas supplies, or even cable television. ESCO
customers would pay for the electricity supply and the transmission
and distribution service, as well as any additional services,
either through two bills one to the regulated T&D
company and one to the ESCO or through a single bill
issued by either the T&D company or the ESCO.
|
|